The average voting rule is a rule for group decision-making when the decision is a distribution (e.g. the allocation of a budget among different issues), and each of the voters reports his ideal distribution. This is a special case of budget-proposal aggregation. It is a simple aggregation rule, that returns the arithmetic mean of all individual ideal distributions. The average rule was first studied formally by Michael Intrilligator.[1] This rule and its variants are commonly used in economics and sports.[2][3]

Characterization

Intrilligator[1] proved that the average rule is the unique rule that satisfies the following three axioms:

  • Completeness: for every n distributions, the rule returns a distribution.
  • Unanimity for losers: if an issue receives 0 in all individual distributions, then it receives 0 in the collective distribution.
  • Strict and equal sensitivity to individual allocations: if one voter increases his allocation to one issue, while all other allocations remain the same, then the collective allocation to this issue strictly increases; moreover, the rate of increase is the same for all voters - it depends only on the issue.

Manipulation

An important disadvantage of the average rule is that it is not strategyproof - it is easy to manipulate.[4] For example, suppose there are two issues, the ideal distribution of Alice is (80%,20%), and the average of the ideal distributions of the other voters is (60%,40%). Then Alice would be better-off by reporting that her ideal distribution is (100%,0%), since this will pull the average distribution closer to her ideal distribution.

If all voters try to manipulate simultaneously, the computed average may be substantially different than the "real" average. Renault and Trannoy[4] study the amount of discrepancy between them.

Variants

The weighted average rule gives different weights to different voters (e.g. based on their level of expertise).

The trimmed average rule discards some of the extreme bids, and returns the average of the remaining bids.

Renault and Trannoy[3] study the combined use of the average rule and the majority rule, and their effect on minority protection.

Other rules

Rosar[2] compares the average voting rule to the median voting rule, when the voters have diverse private information and interdependent preferences. For uniformly distributed information, the average report dominates the median report from a utilitarian perspective, when the set of admissible reports is designed optimally. For general distributions, the results still hold when there are many agents.

See also

References

  1. 1 2 Intriligator, M. D. (1973-10-01). "A Probabilistic Model of Social Choice". The Review of Economic Studies. 40 (4): 553–560. doi:10.2307/2296588. ISSN 0034-6527. JSTOR 2296588.
  2. 1 2 Rosar, Frank (2015-09-01). "Continuous decisions by a committee: Median versus average mechanisms". Journal of Economic Theory. 159: 15–65. doi:10.1016/j.jet.2015.05.010. ISSN 0022-0531.
  3. 1 2 Renault, Regis; Trannoy, Alain (May 2005). "Protecting Minorities through the Average Voting Rule". Journal of Public Economic Theory. 7 (2): 169–199. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9779.2005.00200.x. ISSN 1097-3923.
  4. 1 2 Renault, Régis; Trannoy, Alain (2011-12-01). "Assessing the extent of strategic manipulation: the average vote example". SERIEs. 2 (4): 497–513. doi:10.1007/s13209-011-0077-0. hdl:10419/77720. ISSN 1869-4195.
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.