Original meaning of the word Monopoly comes from Greek as a compound of two words “mono,” which means “single” or “one,” and “polein“, meaning “ to sell.[1]“ This word was perceived as an exclusive legal right of sale covered by Government usually ensured by patent or licence. In the seventeenth century was monopoly defined by sir Edward Coke as “allowance by the King to any person or corporate for the sole buying, selling, making, working or using anything, whereby any person or corporate are sought to be restrained of any freedom or liberty that they had before.[2]” In the eighteenth century was developed another definition by Samuel Johnson as “exclusive privilege of selling anything.[3]” In the course of time has monopoly become interpreted as a private accumulation of economic power or an entity that has total or near-total control of a market.[4]

England

For the first time, monopolies have become socially significant in the early seventeenth century in England under the reign of Queen Elizabeth I. and King James I. who were selling monopolistic licences as a benefit for their own enrichment.[5] The result was a significant increase of prices in particular industries accompanied by enforcing rest of suppliers not to produce, often affected by strict punishments for patent infringement.[6] Long disputation about the efficiency of royal grants of monopoly privileges have been led and finally with the contribution, among others, of Darcy v. Allen and sir Edward Coke royal rights on providing licences have been strictly restraint. Undesirable effects of diminishing social wealth were discussed and new theory of monopolies have begun to be created.

Colonial America

Although most parts of the British law was commonly used as identical in colonies, monopolistic part was not clearly defined in America therefore new specific versions of both patents for economic development and restrictions on the issuance of patents have been enacted. As an example could state Massachusetts’s body of Liberty[7] from 1641 which declared no monopolies are acceptable except for new inventions that are profitable to the country. While leaderships of American colonies began to issue amendments to the law in form of charters and relations with Britain continued to deteriorate, constantly emitted monopolies on England’s suppliers became direct cause of American’s indignation. When England enacted set of laws[8] enabling domestic merchants of many branches to sell with monopoly in British colonies, plenty black markets have arisen accompanied with protests. Well-known is the protest in Boston called Boston Tea Party reacting on raising of taxes, the main target was indeed British government and East India company owning a monopoly over tea import.[9] Continuous efforts to discredit Americans to compete in foreign markets and to secure benefits associated with it have led to the American revolution and the consequent rise of the United states.

Post-industrial monopoly

Process of creating powerful private monopolistic corporates fulfilling a definition of modern monopoly according to its economic position and market power are mostly connected with second half of nineteenth and twentieth century in United States. Public concerns about the state-granted monopolies shifted to fear of private ones. Several of the emerging economic giants such as Standard Oil or Carnegie Steel Company[10] had become so influential on the market that American government had to create new section of antitrust laws to prevent from diminishing social wealth. Most important laws of that time are the Sherman Antitrust Act[11] in 1890 and the Clayton Antitrust Act[12] in 1914. Many constitution have been modified to meet current monopoly requirements, for example Minnesota Constitution stated in 1888: “Any combination of persons, either as individuals or members or officers of any corporation to monopolize the markets for food products in this state, or to interfere with, or to restrict the freedom of such markets, is hereby declared to be a criminal conspiracy and shall be punished in such manner as the Legislature shall provide.[13]” Within this period have been both monopolies and government antitrust laws modified and spread into the whole world even more with trend of globalization. Corporates are consistently observed currently to comply with antitrust measures because the extended modern economic theory proved that an uncontrolled monopoly diminish public wealth.[14]

See also

References

  1. Algeo, John; Barnhart, Robert K.; Steinmetz, Sol (December 1989). "The Barnhart Dictionary of Etymology". Language. 65 (4): 848. doi:10.2307/414944. ISSN 0097-8507. JSTOR 414944.
  2. Lerch, Kent D. (2020), "Coke, Sir Edward: Institutes of the laws of England", Kindlers Literatur Lexikon (KLL), Stuttgart: J.B. Metzler, pp. 1–2, doi:10.1007/978-3-476-05728-0_11158-1, ISBN 978-3-476-05728-0, S2CID 240724266, retrieved 2021-04-09
  3. "PREFACE TO A DICTIONARY OF THE ENGLISH LANGUAGE (1755)", Samuel Johnson, Yale University Press, pp. 397–417, 2021-01-05, doi:10.2307/j.ctv1b9f5zt.43, ISBN 978-0-300-25800-4, retrieved 2021-04-09
  4. Kenton, Will. "Monopoly". Investopedia. Retrieved 2021-04-09.
  5. "Berufung". Astronomische Nachrichten. 224 (16): 275–276. 1925. doi:10.1002/asna.19252241609. ISSN 0004-6337.
  6. "Lords and Commons", The House of Lords in the Reign of Charles II, Cambridge University Press, pp. 116–142, 1996-08-29, doi:10.1017/cbo9780511560835.008, ISBN 978-0-521-55458-9, retrieved 2021-04-09
  7. Plucknett, Theodore F. T.; Farrand, Max (January 1930). "The Laws and Liberties of Massachusetts". The New England Quarterly. 3 (1): 156. doi:10.2307/359470. ISSN 0028-4866. JSTOR 359470.
  8. Jones, Franklin D. (November 1926). "Historical Development of the Law of Business Competition". The Yale Law Journal. 36 (1): 42–55. doi:10.2307/788174. ISSN 0044-0094. JSTOR 788174.
  9. Ramanaiah, Nerella V.; Detwiler, Fred R. J.; Byravan, Anupama (December 1995). "Sex-Role Orientation and Satisfaction with Life". Psychological Reports. 77 (3_suppl): 1260–1262. doi:10.2466/pr0.1995.77.3f.1260. ISSN 0033-2941. PMID 8643792. S2CID 24181802.
  10. Zeidel, Robert F. (2020-04-15), "Introduction", Robber Barons and Wretched Refuse, Cornell University Press, pp. 1–11, doi:10.7591/cornell/9781501748318.003.0001, ISBN 978-1-5017-4831-8, S2CID 241511341, retrieved 2021-04-09
  11. Townsend, James B. (2019-04-18). Extraterritorial Antitrust: The Sherman Antitrust Act and U.S. Business Abroad. doi:10.4324/9780429051135. ISBN 9780429051135. S2CID 159138005.
  12. Holst, Arthur (2005), "Clayton Antitrust Act", Encyclopedia of White-Collar & Corporate Crime, Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE Publications, Inc., doi:10.4135/9781412914260.n94, ISBN 978-0-7619-3004-4, retrieved 2021-04-09
  13. "Case 401: Art. IV NYC; Art. 35 II amended MAL". Internationales Handelsrecht. 3 (3). 2003-01-24. doi:10.1515/ihr.2003.3.3.147b. ISSN 2193-9527.
  14. "Impacts of Monopoly on Efficiency | Boundless Economics". courses.lumenlearning.com. Retrieved 2021-04-09.
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.